The debate over ECB QE was had when the crisis was at its peak. The motivating factor then was ensuring the euro stayed together. Now the motivating factor is low inflation/fear of deflation and low growth. The ultimate conclusion back then was that QE is not the right policy for the ECB (compared to the Fed or the BoE) for a number of practical and political reasons.
Despite the current motivation behind the debate being different, we think the key constraints still hold, while other issues over the effectiveness of QE have also come into play. Our previous thoughts are here. Below we restate our points and add some new insights.
Hard to target QE on the necessary sovereign debt: As we stressed in our previous post and note on this, any QE in terms of direct primary market purchases of eurozone sovereign debt would have to be shared out according to each countries share of ECB capital – i.e. Germany and France would see the large majority of purchases. This significantly limits any real benefit in the periphery and could worsen the crunch for safe assets in the eurozone with the price of core eurozone sovereign debt being driven even higher (and the returns going further down). The hope would be that this would spur investment in the periphery countries but given the investment patterns in Europe and the upcoming stress tests, it’s clear that demand for periphery debt remains separate from demand for core debt.
QE is very different to OMT: The exact constraints for OMT remain ill defined, but what we do know is that any purchases will be limited to short term (below 3 year maturity) debt on the secondary market, will be subject to the strict constraints of a bailout programme and the purchases will be sterilised. What form a QE programme would take is also unclear, however, it is likely to involve significant and widespread purchases which come with no conditions and are not sterilised.
QE on private assets might have little impact in Europe: Unlike the US and even the UK, the European market for securities is far less developed. Furthermore, the corporate sector relies much more heavily on bank loans for funding than on debt issuance (see graph to the right). If the ECB decided on a QE programme to target different securities, the impact on the real economy would be limited by the structure of these markets. This point is driven home by the graph to the right below, which highlights the broad breakdown of assets in the eurozone - significantly dominated by government debt. The ECB could purchase mortgage backed securities, which is one of the more developed markets. However, a significant chunk remain non-performing (or close) and are opaque in terms of what is included inside them and what their true market price is. In all likelihood any purchasing of private sector assets would mostly be a boost to bank balance sheets, however, unless it is sufficient to completely reverse their deleveraging and kick start lending it would probably do more than push up asset prices.For these reasons, we believe QE will be a very last resort for the ECB. It is practically and politically difficult. That said, it still seems like further easing is very much being considered. See for example the Bloomberg story today about the very real possibility of a negative deposit rate (which has weakened the euro significantly). Such a move would itself of course come with drawbacks and difficulties, but we’ll leave them for another post.
Political obstacles are significant: The programme would need approval in the ECB’s Governing Council. With a quarter already known to be against last month’s rate cut, opposition to such a significant step could grow. Even if it got through the fallout in terms of divisions within the ECB and the political blowback from within Germany could create serious problems for the eurozone. Bundesbank President Jens Weidmann even said earlier today that the ECB should not take further easing steps in the near future after the rate cut.
The overall impact on the real economy is far from clear: the discussion over this point in the US and UK has been substantial, with no clear winner. While QE did likely help to avert a deeper crisis, particularly in the short term, the fact is that there is no clear link between higher inflation or higher growth and asset purchases of the central banks.
This is a good review of the arguments against an ECB policy of QE.
ReplyDeleteI have one remark about sterilisation. You point out that OMT purchases would be sterilised but QE (presumably) not. Let's presume the sterilisation we are talking about is as practiced in respect of the earlier SMP purchases. i.e. the ECB accepts rolling 1-week fixed deposits of total value equal to the assets purchased. But the deposits are no less liquid than the reserve balances that they replace, particularly as they are eligible as collateral for ECB refinancing. The sterilisation is cosmetic. Hence, I don't believe the issue of sterilisation is relevant to a discussion of possible ECB-QE.
@ John
ReplyDeleteThanks for the comment. Yes, fair point about the sterilisation, it is largely semantic as you say. The ECB does still insist that in the data (which is unpublished so all we have is their word) they don’t see significant amounts of deposits being used as collateral. In any case, the sterilisation is unlikely to be a big distinguishing factor between QE and OMT, the main differences will likely come in the breadth of assets purchased and the lack of conditions.
The stress tests of bank balance sheets will essentially be about going to banks and valuing their assets. If the banks have valued their assets to high then the stress tests are intended to correct that problem.
ReplyDeleteIf assets can't be accurately valued for a possible QE-situation, can those same assets be accurately valued for a bank stress-test?
QE is about inflating the value of the asset being bought by making those assets 'safe'. However, the risk of owning that assets hasn't disappeared, the risk has simply been transferred to the tax-payers.
QE is yet another sign of an upside down world - safe things like utilities are to be privatised while the general public is to instead take on crazy risks by buying a huge amount of risky financial assets.
The main problem is that the ECB has lost the Southern borders.
ReplyDeleteTheir standard policies simply donot work properly (far from that) overthere.
The only thing that works is the 'do what it takes' stuff.
However that is highly indirectly (much more than the standard stuff or QE).
Nearly impossible to work with dosage.
If the ECB would blink it could be gone in a day. So if it would become operational and it is conditions galore (as it likely will be) markets could lose their confidence.
Very difficult enviroment to operate in. From the ECB's own kitchen so we not really have to be sorry for them.
QE can be 'dosaged', however the effects are nowhere near to the what it takes ones on sov debt at least.
Markets are on Prozac and Coke at the moment, you need to plan over longer and more stable periods.
Anyway the stuff is imho still pretty dodgy legally. Reporters getting bored of it doesnot make it one bit less dodgy. Not only Germany. Financing is for 99% of the world being a creditor and not actually paying (what the ECB makes of it). Until this is cleared it remains highly risky.
And legal certainties need much more time to become clear than economic ones (and they donot have that time).